Entrepreneurs build their business within the context of an
environment which they sometimes may not be able to control. The
robustness of an entrepreneurial venture is tried and tested by the
vicissitudes of the environment. Within the environment are forces that
may serve as great opportunities or menacing threats to the survival of
the entrepreneurial venture. Entrepreneurs need to understand the
environment within which they operate so as to exploit emerging
opportunities and mitigate against potential threats.
This
article serves to create an understanding of the forces at play and
their effect on banking entrepreneurs in Zimbabwe. A brief historical
overview of banking in Zimbabwe is carried out. The impact of the
regulatory and economic environment on the sector is assessed. An
analysis of the structure of the banking sector facilitates an
appreciation of the underlying forces in the industry.
Historical Background
At independence (1980) Zimbabwe had a
sophisticated banking and financial market, with commercial banks mostly
foreign owned. The country had a central bank inherited from the
Central Bank of Rhodesia and Nyasaland at the winding up of the
Federation.
For the first few years of independence, the
government of Zimbabwe did not interfere with the banking industry.
There was neither nationalisation of foreign banks nor restrictive
legislative interference on which sectors to fund or the interest rates
to charge, despite the socialistic national ideology. However, the
government purchased some shareholding in two banks. It acquired
Nedbank's 62% of Rhobank at a fair price when the bank withdrew from the
country. The decision may have been motivated by the desire to
stabilise the banking system. The bank was re-branded as Zimbank. The
state did not interfere much in the operations of the bank. The State in
1981 also partnered with Bank of Credit and Commerce International
(BCCI) as a 49% shareholder in a new commercial bank, Bank of Credit and
Commerce Zimbabwe (BCCZ). This was taken over and converted to
Commercial Bank of Zimbabwe (CBZ) when BCCI collapsed in 1991 over
allegations of unethical business practices.
This should not be
viewed as nationalisation but in line with state policy to prevent
company closures. The shareholdings in both Zimbank and CBZ were later
diluted to below 25% each.
In the first decade, no indigenous bank was licensed and there is no
evidence that the government had any financial reform plan. Harvey
(n.d., page 6) cites the following as evidence of lack of a coherent
financial reform plan in those years:
- In 1981 the government stated that it would encourage rural banking services, but the plan was not implemented.
- In 1982 and 1983 a Money and Finance Commission was proposed but never constituted.
- By 1986 there was no mention of any financial reform agenda in the Five Year National Development Plan.
Harvey
argues that the reticence of government to intervene in the financial
sector could be explained by the fact that it did not want to jeopardise
the interests of the white population, of which banking was an integral
part. The country was vulnerable to this sector of the population as it
controlled agriculture and manufacturing, which were the mainstay of
the economy. The State adopted a conservative approach to indigenisation
as it had learnt a lesson from other African countries, whose economies
nearly collapsed due to forceful eviction of the white community
without first developing a mechanism of skills transfer and capacity
building into the black community. The economic cost of inappropriate
intervention was deemed to be too high. Another plausible reason for the
non- intervention policy was that the State, at independence, inherited
a highly controlled economic policy, with tight exchange control
mechanisms, from its predecessor. Since control of foreign currency
affected control of credit, the government by default, had a strong
control of the sector for both economic and political purposes; hence it
did not need to interfere.
Financial Reforms
However, after
1987 the government, at the behest of multilateral lenders, embarked on
an Economic and Structural Adjustment Programme (ESAP). As part of this
programme the Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe (RBZ) started advocating
financial reforms through liberalisation and deregulation. It contended
that the oligopoly in banking and lack of competition, deprived the
sector of choice and quality in service, innovation and efficiency.
Consequently, as early as 1994 the RBZ Annual Report indicates the
desire for greater competition and efficiency in the banking sector,
leading to banking reforms and new legislation that would:
- allow for the conduct of prudential supervision of banks along international best practice
- allow for both off-and on-site bank inspections to increase RBZ's Banking Supervision function and
- enhance competition, innovation and improve service to the public from banks.
Subsequently
the Registrar of Banks in the Ministry of Finance, in liaison with the
RBZ, started issuing licences to new players as the financial sector
opened up. From the mid-1990s up to December 2003, there was a flurry of
entrepreneurial activity in the financial sector as indigenous owned
banks were set up. The graph below depicts the trend in the numbers of
financial institutions by category, operating since 1994. The trend
shows an initial increase in merchant banks and discount houses,
followed by decline. The increase in commercial banks was initially
slow, gathering momentum around 1999. The decline in merchant banks and
discount houses was due to their conversion, mostly into commercial
banks.
Source: RBZ Reports
Different entrepreneurs used
varied methods to penetrate the financial services sector. Some started
advisory services and then upgraded into merchant banks, while others
started stockbroking firms, which were elevated into discount houses.
From
the beginning of the liberalisation of the financial services up to
about 1997 there was a notable absence of locally owned commercial
banks. Some of the reasons for this were:
- Conservative licensing
policy by the Registrar of Financial Institutions since it was risky to
licence indigenous owned commercial banks without an enabling
legislature and banking supervision experience.
- Banking entrepreneurs opted for non-banking financial institutions
as these were less costly in terms of both initial capital requirements
and working capital. For example a merchant bank would require less
staff, would not need banking halls, and would have no need to deal in
costly small retail deposits, which would reduce overheads and reduce
the time to register profits. There was thus a rapid increase in
non-banking financial institutions at this time, e.g. by 1995 five of
the ten merchant banks had commenced within the previous two years. This
became an entry route of choice into commercial banking for some, e.g.
Kingdom Bank, NMB Bank and Trust Bank.
No comments:
Post a Comment